Rationale for Establishing Malaysian GLCs
M. Bakri Musa
www.bakrimusa.com
Late in the Mahathir Administration the
government embarked on an ambitious “transformation” (that overused word
again!) exercise aimed at, well, transforming GLCs. It is noteworthy that in
all official publications on the matter, including its “Silver Book” and “GLC
Transformation Manual,” there is no mention of the original principles or
rationales behind the setting up of these GLCs.
It is obvious
that the government and those currently managing these GLCs have lost sight of
the original mission. No surprise than that those objectives have remained
unaccomplished; they have been forgotten.
When Tun Razak
conceived the idea of GLCs back in the 1960s he had three major objectives. First
was to spearhead Malay engagement in commerce generally and the corporate
sector specifically. Second, he wanted to level the economic playing field by
breaking the monopolies and monopsonies of the huge colonial firms (as well as the
few Chinese ones) thus easing the entry of new players (meaning Malays). Third,
he wanted to bypass the Byzantine ways and lumbering pace of the civil service.
While merdeka immediately changed Malaysia’s
political atmosphere, there was no comparable accompanying changes in the
economic. Its commanding heights, from plantations to finance, remained entrenched
in colonial hands. The only local firms that could come close to challenge
those colonial entities were the few large Chinese ones. With the withdrawal of
political protection for colonial firms, the existing Chinese companies
blossomed. Like capitalists everywhere, they too were prone to collusion, aided
greatly by their clan organizations and cultural tradition of guanxi (personal
connections).
Even if there
were enterprising Malays, they would not be able to compete against the clan
mentality of existing Chinese enterprises. Like others, those Chinese
businessmen were not in the least tolerating or welcoming of new competitors,
especially those not of their own kind.
There was an
enterprising Malay entrepreneur, “Loya” (lawyer) Maarof, (after whom Bangsar’s
Jalan Maarof was named), who started a Malay bank and a string of Malay
enterprises in Negri Sembilan. He was a bright man whose talent was earlier
spotted by the British; he was sent to Britain to read law. He was also well
versed in economics and knew the importance of having a Malay bank to act as an
intermediary as well as catalyst for Malay economic development. More to the
point, he was able to mobilize the Malay masses or at least interest them in
matters economic. All other Malay leaders at the time (and even today) were
intoxicated with political power, specifically then the pursuit for
independence. Maarof was the rare exception; he recognized early that unless
Malays were also serious players in the Malaysian economy, merdeka would
be a hollow victory. He was particularly prescient.
Somebody must
have viewed him a serious threat on the economic front, for he was soon found
hung in Gombak. The official verdict: suicide. Not many believed that.
Not much has
been written about this bright enterprising young lawyer. He was of my father’s
vintage. All I knew about him was what my father told me when I was growing up.
Not many Malay leaders at that time impressed my father. To him they were all
good only at giving rousing (berkobar-kobar) speeches. Maarof was again the
rare exception; he was a man of action, especially in the field of mobilizing
Malay savings and starting Malay enterprises.
Maarof’s cruel
fate reflected the then prevailing animalistic “law of the jungle” economic
climate. A decade later Tun Razak too recognized that it would be a formidable
challenge for any Malay (or anyone for that matter) to take on these
established Chinese and colonial players. They had effectively tilted the
economic playing field in their favor. Only the government would have the might
to take them on; thus was born the first GLC. Fifty years later China would use
the same strategy to establish its GLCs to take on the giant Western
transnational corporations.
The third reason for
these GLCs was to overcome or bypass the sluggishness of the civil service. The
rule-crippled civil servants would stymie every development initiative with
their bureaucratic obsession with “rules.” They were simple administrators, not
innovative policymakers, clerks rather than executives. They were preoccupied
with routine stuff; strategic planning and bold new initiatives were alien
concepts to them. To get a simple project going would involve a Byzantine
process, meandering through the convoluted belly of a constipated bureaucracy.
All these inadequacies are well documented in Esman’s book, Administration and Development in Malaysia:
Institution Building and Reform in a Plural Society.
With GLCs
Razak could bypass all of those bureaucratic hoops. He was also able to recruit
fresh young talent to helm these companies. Under the strict civil service code
with its undue deference to seniority, these promising officers would have been
stuck in some junior positions. That was how Tengku Razaleigh was able to head
Bank Bumiputra and later, Petronas, while still in his thirties.
Today, the
only hint of deference to Tun Razak’s original mission was this oblique and
very brief statement in the 49-page “The Summary of Transformation Manual”:
“[T]he principles of growth with equity, ... development of human capital, and
the development of the Bumiputra community.”
To be
generous, Tun Razak’s original mission of spearheading Bumiputra participation
in the private sector could be encompassed under “the development of the
Bumiputra community” umbrella. That aside, the much-hyped “Transformation”
document makes no direct or specific mention to the role of GLCs in today’s
Malaysia. Instead the report focused on profits. Meaning, these GLCs are no
different from any other corporation except for the fact that the government is
their principal shareholder and provider of financial and other capitals, and
also increasingly, their main customer.
The stated
objective of NEP, reiterated ad nauseam, is that there be at least 30 percent
Bumiputra participation in the equity market. GLCs were to be the primary
instrument to achieving that. There is little disagreement that over two
generations later, Bumiputra participation in the private sector, specifically
the equity market, is still well below what is expected based on our share of
the population. It is also well below NEP’s modest target.
That
transformation report made no reference to this abysmal failure. If these GLCs
have failed to achieve their modest goals during the past five decades, it is
unlikely that they will be any more successful in the next five. The only
conclusion, and a crucial one, is that these GLCs are not effective. It is time
we abandon them though the original objectives as laid out in the mission
statement remain valid and worthy of pursuit.
It is time to
liberate our thinking and be bold in our imagination. I suggest that we sell
all these GLCs and put the proceeds in a trust fund for the specific purpose of
enhancing Bumiputra human and social capital. Before fleshing out my proposal,
I will review the impact GLCs have had on Malays. Just in case my idea of
disposing of the GLCs entirely is deemed too radical, I outline my ideas for
newer models as well as offer my alternatives towards achieving the same goals.
Next:
Ratinale for GLCs: Leveling the
Economic Playing Field
Adapted from the author’s book, Liberating
The Malay Mind, published by ZI Publications, Petaling Jaya, 2013.
The second edition was released in January 2016.
0 Comments:
Post a Comment
<< Home