Soft Barriers to Malay Participation In Commerce
M. Bakri Musa
Soft barriers to
active participation in the money economy are especially pronounced in
societies that still exist in or have just exited from the peasantry and
subsistence living. That is Malay society at the time of colonization. It is
still true for a vast segment even today. The concept of money and the “money
economy” is alien to them. Money was equated with greed and unbridled
materialism, not a suitable topic in polite conversations. To ask for the
monetary value of anything or service was tantamount to insulting its owner or
provider. Monetary value was only for showing off your social status as with
how much was your dowry or car.
The traditional
trading activities in such societies are primitive, restricted to bartering.
The worth of such exchanges, as with trading a few coconuts for fixing a leaky
roof, is not with the economic value of the coconuts or the repairing of the
roof, rather the goodwill generated, one fellow villager helping another.
One can
imagine the difficulty members of such a society would have in adjusting to a
money economy. If this were to be imposed from the outside world, as with
colonialism, free-flow immigration, or unrestrained globalization, the
difficulties in adjusting would be compounded.
Typically that
society would react in one of two ways. It either withdraws, effectively
declaring that it does not want anything to do with this alien value system, or
else it blindly embraces the new system enthusiastically and uncritically.
The first
reaction is seen in many Muslim countries, and I will pursue this further in
the section, “Imprisoned by Religion.” We also see this with North American
Indians, India under Nehru, and today’s Myanmar.
With the
second, what typically happens is the absorption of only the superficialities
and excesses, as can be seen in the immediate post-Mao period of China. After
spurning the outside world, China suddenly changed under Deng Xiaoping. In
mature capitalistic societies such as America and Western Europe, there is an
effective taxation system with redistributionist elements, and where
philanthropy is an honored tradition which have evolved and been perfected over
time.
In China (as
in many Third World societies) you are considered stupid if you do not conceal
your income from the government and cheat on your taxes. As for charity, when
Warren Buffet and Bill Gates, two billionaires known for their charitable deeds
as much as their capitalistic instincts, visited China to interest its newly
rich in philanthropy, the pair were greeted with silence if not derision.
America has its Dukes and Stanfords, elite universities that are testaments to
the generosities of their capitalist titans. China has none as yet, and
possibly never will.
It is the rare
society that gets it right immediately. The hope is that it will learn and
stabilize eventually. Otherwise those excesses would lead to instability. The
Chinese leadership today is very much aware of the severe negative consequences
to the excesses and flamboyance of its politburo members and their children,
especially when displayed abroad. There is as yet no such abhorrence with the
excesses, corrupton, and flamboyance of the Malay elite–our sultans and
UMNOputras.
It was only a
generation or two ago that Malay society was deep in its subsistence and
agrarian mode, typical of the kampong lifestyle. Most Malays lived off
the land, and gotong-royong (communal effort) was the norm; bartering or
trading of goods and services were strange concepts. Instead you helped each
other, with no financial considerations.
With the
coming of colonial rule and with it, capitalism, Malays were thrown into the
money economy precipitously without any transition. The later influx of immigrants
further compounded the issue. The immigrants by default and out of necessity
had to adapt to the money economy to survive; they had no social or physical
support system as with Malays and our kampong lifestyle. This earlier
entry into the money economy by the immigrant population conferred significant
advantages vis a vis the native peasant population.
It was no
surprise that Malays, specifically those in UMNO, at the dawn of our country’s
independence were clearly anti-capitalistic, except for its top leader, Tunku
Abdul Rahman, who remained unabashedly committed to capitalism. To those in
UMNO during its infancy, the term kaum kapitalis was derogatory,
comparable and perhaps synonymous with kaum kolonialist (colonialist
class/hordes). That soon changed when they saw the tangible results of profits
and wealth. This Malay embrace of capitalism was accelerated under Mahathir.
Like the
Chinese in China today, Malays embrace only the primitive or animalistic form
of capitalism, its raw and exploitative version, and the associated quick bucks
and short-term mindset. Also akin to modern China, corruption, collusion, and
influence peddling rapidly became the norm.
If those are
not formidable enough obstacles, then there is yet another significant “soft”
barrier to Malay entry into commerce–our religion, or more accurately our
particular and myopic interpretation of the Koran and Hadith (sayings and
practices of Prophet Muhammad, s.a.w.). I will defer this to Part Eight,
“Imprisoned by Religion.” For now, let me quickly preempt the anticipated
reflex criticisms.
As a Muslim, I
believe that my faith is fully consistent with and supportive of the ideals and
practices of capitalism. Nothing in my reading tells me otherwise. After all,
our Prophet Muhammad, s.a.w. (May Allah bless his soul) was a successful trader
before receiving his prophethood. That reflected the profession’s high standing
with Allah as much as His appraisal of the man.
However, being
not an Islamic scholar or an economist, I lack credibility. All I can do is
share with readers what I have learned from others about my faith and its view
on capitalism.
One thing is
certain; Islam cannot be supportive of atheistic communism or its close cousin,
socialism. It is true that the egalitarian ideals of socialism may appeal and
indeed have to many Muslims and can be construed as being consistent with those
of Islam. On closer reading however, equality is not the ideal of Islam; indeed
that would be against human nature. Allah in his wisdom has created us in all
our diversities, with different skin colors, speaking different languages, and
having diverse cultures. He has also endowed us with different talents and
abilities.
Equality in
such a setting would be an elusive goal, as well as a cruel illusion. Those in
power would determine what equality would mean. In America at the time of the
declaration of independence, the “We, the people” phrase in the preamble of its
constitution for whom “equality” would apply were restricted to only tax-paying
white males. They alone were entitled to vote and have the protection of the
constitution. Slaves, women, and those who did not own land were excluded. Only
later was that “equality” extended to them.
Likewise with
meritocracy; those already in power would determine what attributes are
considered meritorious. Meritocracy as a
concept could easily be used to justify continued suppression and denial of
opportunities to others not currently favored.
Islam
emphasizes justice, not equality. We cannot treat an orphan in the same “equal”
manner as the son of a privileged family. That would be the height of
injustice. Indeed to be just, we should do more for the orphan, which would
also be the right thing to do. The great American jurist Oliver Wendell Holmes
said it best, “It is a wise man who said that there is no greater inequality
than the equal treatment of people who are unequal.”
It is easy for
today’s observers, Muslims included, to conclude that Islam is against
capitalism, or at least wealth creation and accumulation. Muslim countries,
even those blessed with abundant natural resources like oil and gas, are overrepresented
in the poor and deprived category. In Malaysia, Malays, who by statutory
definitions are Muslims, lag behind the other races in all socioeconomic
indices. That there was a time when Muslims were ahead of the curve has been
all but forgotten, and if recalled, only for syok sendiri (self-gratification) exercises and
not as a learning opportunity.
Capitalism is
not un-Islamic. On the contrary, many of the practices and consequences of
capitalism are very much in tune with the aspirations of our faith. Both
capitalism and Islam are very adaptive. If the communist Chinese could adopt
capitalism and imbue it with Chinese characteristics and sensibilities, and in
the process emancipate hundreds of millions of its people out of poverty, I
fail to see why we cannot do the same. Meaning, imbue capitalism with Islamic characteristics.
Next:
The Fallacies of GLCs
Adapted from the author’s book, Liberating
The Malay Mind, published by ZI Publications, Petaling Jaya, 2013.
The second edition was released in January 2016.